economic development – Jeffrey C. Goldfarb's Deliberately Considered http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com Informed reflection on the events of the day Sat, 14 Aug 2021 16:22:30 +0000 en-US hourly 1 https://wordpress.org/?v=4.4.23 7 Ways Argentina Defies the Conventional Economic Wisdom http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2012/05/7-ways-argentina-defies-the-conventional-economic-wisdom-2/ http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2012/05/7-ways-argentina-defies-the-conventional-economic-wisdom-2/#respond Fri, 04 May 2012 19:04:37 +0000 http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/?p=13173 Reflections on Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery, by Michael Cohen

My New School colleague Michael Cohen’s new book Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery: The Economy in a Time of Default provides the first detailed account in English of one of the remarkable episodes in recent economic history. Cohen’s rendering of 21st century Argentine political economy is detailed, nuanced, filled with summaries of political debates and standoffs and with a rich appreciation of the unequal ways in which the economic benefits are shared as the Argentine economy recovered from its macroeconomic collapse in 2001.

The book is a fast-paced (at times blow-by-blow) account, of macroeconomic extremes in terms of debt, exchange rates, government budget and trade balances and fiscal and monetary policy in Argentina. But when I finished reading the book (and took a big exhale) what struck me — not an expert on Argentina by any stretch — were the many ways that the Argentine experience contradicts the conventional economic wisdom. Without much explicit attention to issue of conventional economic wisdom (other than the attack on World Bank and IMF structural adjustment policies imposed on Argentina in the 1990s), Cohen’s account nonetheless forces us to think critically about some widely-held views in economics and especially development economics. Let me describe seven different ways in which Argentina’s experience in the 21st century should make us revisit some of the accepted aspects of economic wisdom.

To continue reading Will Milberg’s review of Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery by Michael Cohen, click here.

]]>
Reflections on Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery, by Michael Cohen

My New School colleague Michael Cohen’s new book Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery: The Economy in a Time of Default provides the first detailed account in English of one of the remarkable episodes in recent economic history.  Cohen’s rendering of 21st century Argentine political economy is detailed, nuanced, filled with summaries of political debates and standoffs and with a rich appreciation of the unequal ways in which the economic benefits are shared as the Argentine economy recovered from its macroeconomic collapse in 2001.

The book is a fast-paced (at times blow-by-blow) account, of macroeconomic extremes in terms of debt, exchange rates, government budget and trade balances and fiscal and monetary policy in Argentina.  But when I finished reading the book (and took a big exhale) what struck me — not an expert on Argentina by any stretch — were the many ways that the Argentine experience contradicts the conventional economic wisdom.  Without much explicit attention to issue of conventional economic wisdom (other than the attack on World Bank and IMF structural adjustment policies imposed on Argentina in the 1990s), Cohen’s account nonetheless forces us to think critically about some widely-held views in economics and especially development economics.  Let me describe seven different ways in which Argentina’s experience in the 21st century should make us revisit some of the accepted aspects of economic wisdom.

To continue reading Will Milberg’s review of Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery by Michael Cohen, click here.

]]>
http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2012/05/7-ways-argentina-defies-the-conventional-economic-wisdom-2/feed/ 0
7 Ways Argentina Defies the Conventional Economic Wisdom http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2012/05/7-ways-argentina-defies-the-conventional-economic-wisdom/ http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2012/05/7-ways-argentina-defies-the-conventional-economic-wisdom/#comments Fri, 04 May 2012 19:03:28 +0000 http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/?p=13178 Reflections on Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery, by Michael Cohen

My New School colleague Michael Cohen’s new book Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery: The Economy in a Time of Default provides the first detailed account in English of one of the remarkable episodes in recent economic history. Cohen’s rendering of 21st century Argentine political economy is detailed, nuanced, filled with summaries of political debates and standoffs and with a rich appreciation of the unequal ways in which the economic benefits are shared as the Argentine economy recovered from its macroeconomic collapse in 2001.

The book is a fast-paced (at times blow-by-blow) account, of macroeconomic extremes in terms of debt, exchange rates, government budget and trade balances and fiscal and monetary policy in Argentina. But when I finished reading the book (and took a big exhale) what struck me — not an expert on Argentina by any stretch — were the many ways that the Argentine experience contradicts the conventional economic wisdom. Without much explicit attention to issue of conventional economic wisdom (other than the attack on World Bank and IMF structural adjustment policies imposed on Argentina in the 19990s), Cohen’s account nonetheless forces us to think critically about some widely-held views in economics and especially development economics. Let me describe seven different ways in which Argentina’s experience in the 21st century should make us revisit some of the accepted aspects of economic wisdom.

Conventional wisdom #1. Conventional wisdom is that default on foreign debt will have disastrous consequences for economic growth, economic suicide. The country that defaults, the thinking goes, immediately shuts itself out of international capital markets for an unpredictably long period of time, brings on a long-term collapse of the exchange rate, requires a long-term recession as the country is forced to “live within its means.”

Argentina defaulted in early 2002 and then:

*one year later was borrowing considerable from the World Bank and Inter-American Development Bank.

*between 2002 and 2006 inward FDI rose at a rate of 26% per year (much from Brazil)

*by . . .

Read more: 7 Ways Argentina Defies the Conventional Economic Wisdom

]]>
Reflections on Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery, by Michael Cohen

My New School colleague Michael Cohen’s new book Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery: The Economy in a Time of Default provides the first detailed account in English of one of the remarkable episodes in recent economic history.  Cohen’s rendering of 21st century Argentine political economy is detailed, nuanced, filled with summaries of political debates and standoffs and with a rich appreciation of the unequal ways in which the economic benefits are shared as the Argentine economy recovered from its macroeconomic collapse in 2001.

The book is a fast-paced (at times blow-by-blow) account, of macroeconomic extremes in terms of debt, exchange rates, government budget and trade balances and fiscal and monetary policy in Argentina.  But when I finished reading the book (and took a big exhale) what struck me — not an expert on Argentina by any stretch — were the many ways that the Argentine experience contradicts the conventional economic wisdom.  Without much explicit attention to issue of conventional economic wisdom (other than the attack on World Bank and IMF structural adjustment policies imposed on Argentina in the 19990s), Cohen’s account nonetheless forces us to think critically about some widely-held views in economics and especially development economics.  Let me describe seven different ways in which Argentina’s experience in the 21st century should make us revisit some of the accepted aspects of economic wisdom.

Conventional wisdom #1.  Conventional wisdom is that default on foreign debt will have disastrous consequences for economic growth, economic suicide.  The country that defaults, the thinking goes, immediately shuts itself out of international capital markets for an unpredictably long period of time, brings on a long-term collapse of the exchange rate, requires a long-term recession as the country is forced to “live within its means.”

Argentina defaulted in early 2002 and then:

*one year later was borrowing considerable  from the World Bank and Inter-American Development Bank.

*between 2002 and 2006 inward FDI rose at a rate of 26% per year  (much from Brazil)

*by 2006 was experiencing rapid economic growth rates, funding new social programs aimed at reducing poverty and was considered fiscally very sound.

Conventional wisdom #2.  Conventional wisdom runs that globalization is a process that drastically reduces the power of the nation-state, since increased capital mobility means that capital’s interests no longer coincide with those of the nation state and, anyway, the state’s influence over capital and the economy generally is diminished because capital (and labor) can simply move or shift production locations if domestic policies put it at a disadvantage.

Argentina’s example in a time of default is increased power of the national government, first over the decision to default on foreign debt, and then to run very active jobs and redistributional policy. Nestor Kirchner’s “strong state” was even criticized for being too powerful at time.

Conventional Wisdom #3. A corollary of this conventional wisdom about the diminished power of the nation state in the era of globalization is that one size – that is the neoliberal policy package – fits all.  Fiscal and monetary restraint, current and capital account liberalization, removal of subsidies are the basic requirements of any structural adjustment.  As a result of this thinking (which Cohen shows originated in the US and Europe), these policies became the basics of IMF and World Bank conditionality attached, in one form or another, to loans made throughout the later part of the 20th century.

Cohen’s account of Argentina in the run-up to default is a case of “the (neoliberal) operation was a success but the patient died.”  Hyperinflation was cured but the debt became unsustainable.  Cohen’s account since default is a description of a complicated set of deviations from this policy prescription – and with considerable success: Higher taxes, pro-poor redistribution and spending, job creation programs, loose monetary policy with careful attention to a competitive exchange rate.  This was the political foundation for the rapid growth of the 2000s.

Conventional wisdom #4. Latin American wisdom (from  1950’s structuralist views on economic development made famous in the writings of Raul Prebisch and Hans Singer) says that developing countries should actively seek to avoid a pattern of specialization which is too reliant on commodities and primary goods – they have a low income elasticity of demand and are standardized goods for which no market power and no labor bargaining can take place.

What happened in Argentina in the 2000s was a period of rapid economic recovery strongly supported by the global commodities boom that drove an explosion of exports and which had a considerable multiplier effect across the Argentine economy – continuing to this day.  The terms of trade — driven to a great extent by high world prices for soybeans — is up over 50% in the last decade.  And this has come even in a period of depreciation of the Peso against the Brazilian Real. (Note that Cohen also questions whether the main source of economic growth was domestic demand.  When the peso was devalued in 2002, import substitution took place, raising demand for domestic goods and services.  Government spending also grew.  These, he argues, were the basis for the “demand-led recovery.”

Conventional wisdom #5: With the rise of China, consensus is growing around the view that the autocratic is most able to promote development.  Increasingly, Chinese success is connected to the autocratic nature of the political system.  It is this absence of democratic accountability in China, the conventional wisdom goes, that has allowed the Chinese government the ability and nimbleness to harness labor and capital investment in a massive industrialization effort.  Argentina’s remarkable era of democratically-elected governments belies this consensus view.

Conventional wisdom #6: Conventional economic wisdom is that a tide of economic growth will raise all boats.  The friendly World Bank amendment to this has been that one also needs good institutions, i.e. clear property rights protections.  The conventional wisdom is that economic growth per se is the central means to the improvement of well-being and the reduction of poverty.

The Argentine case shows that growth alone was not adequate and Cohen attributes progress on the poverty and employment front to Kirchner government efforts to support housing, health care, job creation, social protection and infrastructure.

Conventional wisdom #7. Conventional wisdom is that the international financial institutions are more powerful than domestic political forces – thus the old joke that the World Bank has brought down more governments than have national revolutionary movements.

Cohen’s account tells the fascinating story of a country that defaults on its foreign debt in the face of enormous IMF pressure not to do so.  Then, just a few years later, the government elected with the largest plurality in decades finds itself in an unwinnable battle about export taxes with the powerful and large domestic farmers.  These huge corporations, profiting greatly during the commodities boom of the 2000’s succeed with a lockout (keeping produce and meat off the domestic market), protests, influence peddling in the Senate, control of the media.  So what’s new?  Argentina defies the conventional wisdom.

Perhaps what is the most unconventional part of this book is the way Cohen tells the economic story of Argentina in a time of default.  Contrary to the economists, Cohen argues that all economic processes must be understood as political, that economic change comes generally with a “major realignment of political power.” Even more interesting is Cohen’s insistence that you can’t assess economic policy in some pure way, but only in the context of its institutional and political overlay.  This leads him to strongly resist the notion of the end of history or the end of politics in Latin America.  The book resounds with a very hopeful view of the possibilities of creativity and innovation in policy making and poverty reduction, management up urban development, but also with a realistic sense of the limits of politics.

Cohen’s views on these issues are closest to those of Peter Evans and his notion of “embedded autonomy.” The idea is that the most effective developmental states are those most closely connected to economic and civil society actors, but which also have sufficient autonomy  (a) to be able to implement policy effectively even when the impact of a policy shift is not favorable to one or more group of actors, and (b) to implement policies with long-term developmental consequences rather than short-term ones. Embedded autonomy is a particularly useful lens with which to think about economic policy making in Argentina, with its history of Peronism, military dictatorship and now a vigorous democracy.  Embedded autonomy remains particularly relevant in the Kirchner era, which at various moments was accused of being too embedded and at times too autonomous.

Finally, I would be remiss if I didn’t speak of Cohen’s own problem of “embedded autonomy.”  Cohen has been personally friendly with the Kirchner’s over many years and  they have supported the Latin American Observatory at the New School.  So the big question as I opened the cover of the book for the first time was whether Cohen would pull his punches in his assessment of the Kirchner governments.  The answer is that he does not hide his colors – he is mostly supportive of the Kirchner governments and their efforts at redistribution and poverty alleviation.  But he does this within a distinct analytical frame and from a clear sense of principles – that economic growth alone does not alleviate problems of extreme inequality, persistent poverty and lack of access to health care.  While the rapid recovery following default is remarkable, Cohen does not let the reader lose sight of the perhaps more remarkable feat which is the recovery from a brutal military dictatorship in 1976-1983 to a strong democracy that seems to have come not just with ambitions of voting rights but also of economic rights.  And he is critical of the Kirchner’s in a number of places, mostly for ignoring important aspects of long-term social well-being related to the development of science and technology, infrastructure and the apparent collapse of energy production over the last decade that may cripple the economy going forward.

Recent economic reports indicate that Argentina is once more on the edge:  The economy may well be spiraling into another crisis — exchange rate overvalued once again, capital flight, expansionary fiscal policy, inflation taking off.  Rumor is that the government may be falsifying the published rate of price inflation.  And while Cohen covers the politics of this in much detail, he is insufficiently critical of the government in its dangerous politicization of inflation data.  The recent law regarding the accountability of the central bank makes sense in that public accountability is in general a good thing, but the political pressures this creates for monetary policy to finance public deficits are not necessarily good over the long term.

Argentina’s Economic Growth and Recovery: The Economy in a Time of Default reflects a deep appreciation for the political culture, the economic history, the geographical complexity, the class differences and the international pressures that Argentines have struggled with over the past two decades.  It is an important treatise in political economy and Cohen tells it in detail and with a lot of passion and even, at times, frustration.  My sense is that these two sentiments – passion and frustration — are conventional sentiments for most Argentines.

]]>
http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2012/05/7-ways-argentina-defies-the-conventional-economic-wisdom/feed/ 3
Uruguay at the Crossroads: No Justice without Development http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2011/07/uruguay-at-the-crossroads-no-justice-without-development/ http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2011/07/uruguay-at-the-crossroads-no-justice-without-development/#respond Wed, 13 Jul 2011 23:00:00 +0000 http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/?p=6385 In this post, Antonio Álvarez considers an enduring problem, the relationship between social justice and development in a country moving from dictatorship to democracy. This problem was pressing during the transitions in Latin America and the former Soviet bloc. It endures, as is evident here. The circumstances are always very specific, but the difficulties repeat themselves as is now dramatically evident in North Africa and the Middle East. A creative approach to the difficulties is considered here. -Jeff

Memory and development often seem to be in tension in Latin America. The left speaks of the need to remember the past, particularly the human rights abuses committed by dictatorships during the cold war; the right, on the other hand, is concerned that an obsession with memory will forestall economic growth. A few weeks ago, Gerardo Bleier published, via Facebook, a piece that made the old-guard of the Uruguayan left quite uncomfortable. In the post, he presented a strong and provocative argument concerning collective memory and economic development. A leftist in distinguished standing, Bleier argues that in order to achieve justice concerning human rights violations during the recent Uruguayan dictatorship, Uruguayans must focus on social and economic development. Development, he argues, ought to be seen as an instrument of justice. He has thus rejected the common sense positions of the left and the right and maps out a significant alternative.

Bleier has been a noted Uruguayan journalist since the 1980s. During the first government of the Frente Amplio (Broad Front, the left of center coalition), led by socialist Tabaré Vázquez (2005-2010), Bleier served as a high level consultant; and currently, he publishes weekly reflections about the vicissitudes encountered by the present Frente Amplio.

Importantly, he is the son of Eduardo Bleier, who was a high ranking cadre in the Communist Party. Without ever having held a gun, Eduardo was one of the many activists who disappeared, was tortured, and murdered during Uruguay’s “dirty war” of the 1960s and 1970s. He probably died the first week of July, 1976, though no one knows for sure. After being tortured in the most . . .

Read more: Uruguay at the Crossroads: No Justice without Development

]]>
In this post, Antonio Álvarez considers an enduring problem, the relationship between social justice and development in a country moving from dictatorship to democracy. This problem was pressing during the transitions in Latin America and the former Soviet bloc. It endures, as is evident here. The circumstances are always very specific, but the difficulties repeat themselves as is now dramatically evident in North Africa and the Middle East. A creative approach to the difficulties is considered here. -Jeff


Memory and development often seem to be in tension in Latin America. The left speaks of the need to remember the past, particularly the human rights abuses committed by dictatorships during the cold war; the right, on the other hand, is concerned that an obsession with memory will forestall economic growth.  A few weeks ago, Gerardo Bleier published, via Facebook, a piece that made the old-guard of the Uruguayan left quite uncomfortable.  In the post, he presented a strong and provocative argument concerning collective memory and economic development. A leftist in distinguished standing, Bleier argues that in order to achieve justice concerning human rights violations during the recent Uruguayan dictatorship, Uruguayans must focus on social and economic development. Development, he argues, ought to be seen as an instrument of justice.  He has thus rejected the common sense positions of the left and the right and maps out a significant alternative.

Bleier has been a noted Uruguayan journalist since the 1980s. During the first government of the Frente Amplio (Broad Front, the left of center coalition), led by socialist Tabaré Vázquez (2005-2010), Bleier served as a high level consultant; and currently, he publishes weekly reflections about the vicissitudes encountered by the present Frente Amplio.

Importantly, he is the son of Eduardo Bleier, who was a high ranking cadre in the Communist Party. Without ever having held a gun, Eduardo was one of the many activists who disappeared, was tortured, and murdered during Uruguay’s “dirty war” of the 1960s and 1970s.  He probably died the first week of July, 1976, though no one knows for sure. After being tortured in the most savage way, he was thrown into a small wooden box and buried alive. The family never saw his remains. It is rumored that he was buried in a clandestine cemetery located within an army compound assigned to Battalion 13 of the Infantry Division. At some point between October 1984 and March 1985, as democracy was being reestablished, Bleier’s body was unearthed and transferred to a different military compound. Later, his body was unearthed yet again, together with the bodies of several military officers. This time his remains were incinerated and thrown into the Río de la Plata, according to some versions, or into a nearby creek, according to others.

The son’s political judgment is of course shaped and informed by his father’s fate. In his recent post, Eduardo Bleier provided a personal and poignant reflection about the meaning of memory and justice in Uruguay. He writes:

It is obvious that this [growth] should not prevent us from weaving and reconstructing the collective memories pertaining to the civil war and to the terrorism that was perpetrated by the state. We cannot stop reminding ourselves of the scale of this state-sponsored terrorism, which many have tried to hide, and the systematic violation of human rights, which occurred during the dictatorship. We can’t stop trying to find avenues that would lead us to the missing truths. We can’t stop debunking the politics of silence and protection of criminals. Yet, these themes cannot occupy the central stage in Uruguayan politics, as Uruguayans essentially understand.

I agree with Bleier’s most provocative point: addressing the problems of the past should not distract us from the need for development. Uruguay has to address its problematic past, but it cannot be careless about issues of poverty and institutional life in the future. We have to remember, but we also have to develop. After all, Uruguay was, for 70 years, on the forefront of education, and yet today it experiences a grotesque decline of its educational system; a decline that coincides with a previous collapse of the economy and the subsequent process of polarization which led to 12 years of dictatorship.

Bleier also wrote this in his Facebook account:

[I]t is also true that the overwhelming majority of Uruguayans, particularly the youth, need a collective memory that is not marked by the traumas of the past, but by the challenges of the future.

His post generated strong responses, in favor and against, among readers who are mostly intellectuals and activists with bright futures. The debate took place just as the Administration of President José Mujica –a former militant of the guerrilla group Tupamaros— lost a battle, failing to pass legislation that would allow the judiciary to prosecute members of the military who, during the civil war, committed crimes against humanity. The legislation was designed to reverse the amnesty law that was approved in 1985, shortly after democracy was reestablished in Uruguay. This amnesty law had allowed for a peaceful transition from 12 years of military rule to a democratic form of governance.  In essence, this law was a form of extortion, whereby the dictatorship protected its members from being judged for crimes against humanity.

Mujica’s predecesor, Tabaré Vázquez, had begun the legislative process intended to reopen cases of human rights violations that involved members of the dictatorship. As a result of Vázquez’ initiative, 28 police officers and members of the military who worked for the dictatorship have been jailed in a military detention center. Among them are lower-level functionaries, intelligence service operators, some police officers, a former Chancellor, Juan Carlos Blanco, and two former presidents, Juan Maria Bordaberry (under house arrest), and Lieutenant General Gregorio Alvarez.

Yet, of course, these people were not the only ones who were responsible for disappearances, torture and murders. According to the Freedom and Concord Forum (Foro Libertad y Concordia), an association that allegedly represents retired military, more than 400 military officers and soldiers are needed to serve as witnesses, in case Mujica’s government prosecutes the 88 members of the military whose cases have been pending. The spokesman of the association, retired Colonel Juan Perez de Azziz expects that dozens of these witnesses have a chance of ending up in jail themselves.

Today Uruguayans are confronted precisely with the question of whether or not to proceed with this amnesty law, of whether to focus on their past or to focus on their future.

After all these years, Gerardo Bleier knows that those responsible for his father’s torture and death are not just the politically alienated and the ultra-nationalist members of the military; the small cadre that operated during the cold war. He knows that political groups and people with economic interests also added fuel to the terror, people whose names can fill countless pages, even tomes that may never be part of our history. The government of the United States, to begin with, was the main facilitator of this crisis, having financed, since 1968, our Homeland Security Program, under which Uruguayan officers were trained by CIA operatives.

Ever since, many historical events have met their expiration date. And Bleier, the survivor, knows well that each passing day truth flees yet again. But he also knows that there will be no truth and no justice if Uruguay doesn’t consolidate its future. And he knows that this future and these truths will not be possible if we don’t take care today of our current, important, urgent demands: educate the young, address the problems of gross inequality, develop the economy.  These are not tasks that turn away from remembering the past. They are preconditions for it.

]]>
http://www.deliberatelyconsidered.com/2011/07/uruguay-at-the-crossroads-no-justice-without-development/feed/ 0